INST Committee Report
If you have any questions or comments regarding the accessibility of this publication, please contact us at accessible@parl.gc.ca.
CHAPTER 7: MERGER REVIEW
The Competition Act provides for the civil review of mergers (sections 91 through 96) by the Competition Tribunal. On application by the Commissioner of Competition, the Tribunal may issue a prohibition or divestiture order with respect to a merger that is deemed to prevent or lessen competition substantially. However, before such orders are granted, varied or denied by the Tribunal, a well-established review process must take place. As a starting point, the Committee will provide a simple sketch of this merger review process, which will provide the necessary background to comment on the operations and enforcement of the merger provisions in the Act. Section 91 of the Competition Act sets forth the definition of a merger, which is deemed to occur when direct or indirect control over, or significant interest in, the whole or a part of a business of another person is acquired or established. The principal issue in this section is the interpretation of the words significant interest, which is considered to occur when a person acquires or establishes the ability to materially influence the economic behaviour of the business of a second person (i.e., block Director resolutions or make executive decisions relating to pricing, purchasing, distribution, marketing or investment). In general, a direct or indirect holding of less than a 10% voting interest in another entity will not be considered a significant interest. However, a significant interest may be acquired or established pursuant to shareholder agreements, management contracts and other contractual arrangements involving incorporated or non-incorporated entities. In general, a merger will be found to be likely to prevent or lessen competition substantially when the parties to the merger would more likely be in a position to exercise a materially greater degree of market power in a substantial part of a market for two years or more. Market power can be exercised unilaterally or interdependently with other competitors and its ascertainment will be determined according to the following Bureau screening processes: |
On the other issue, from an enforcement perspective,
theres a lot of discussion in the business about how few cases there are and how
much guidance is available to the public at large and the business and consumer legal
communities about how decisions are made. This issue has been debated probably longer than
private access, but I think its time we institute some form of formal decision
publication process. [George Addy, Osler, Hoskin & Harcourt, 59:11:15]
The EU has a process
where, even though a transaction isnt challenged, a decision is released describing
how the agency went through its review, what its findings were, and what it considered
important or not important. I think that would serve as a very useful public information
service for the Bureau to adopt. [George Addy, Osler, Hoskin & Harcourt, 59:11:15] |
|
The Bureau does publish, in each merger case, aspects
of its decision. What people are saying is theres not enough core analysis
necessarily there for us to judge the next case. The contest, however, is how much can you
disclose of the confidential information that gives rise to the analysis? [Robert
Russell, Borden, Ladner & Gervais, 59:12:05] [W]hen
youre sitting in the room negotiating the resolution, you also talk about what
should be published, and it can interfere with some of the remedy. If youre having
to divest of a core asset, if you put too much out there, it becomes a fire sale, which
makes it more difficult to resolve. If youre going to give me a penny for my asset
or $100 million for my asset, youre going to have a different negotiation coming up
with a resolution. [Robert Russell, Borden, Ladner & Gervais, 59:12:10] |
28 | There is no economic rationale for these thresholds over that of others. Simply put, an effective merger review process demands market share anchors, but why these thresholds were chosen over others has never been made clear. |
Merger Review Workload and Service Standards Virtually every witness appearing before the Committee admitted that the Bureau has faced an unprecedented number of merger reviews over the past several years, which has, and continues to put, extraordinary pressure on its Mergers Branch staff. Table 7.1 provides the data to back up the first part of this claim. Excluding asset securitizations (which, since 1999, have been exempted from filing), merger filings have hovered about 340 per annum in the past four years, which is up more than 70% from the average of about 200 filings per year recorded in the first half of the 1990s. So the trend is definitely up over the past decade, but it is also up over the past five years, with 373 mergers being filed in 2000-2001, the highest ever. |
[U]nder a total surplus
approach, the Competition Tribunal would be prohibited from issuing an order in respect of
an anti-competitive merger if it found that the overall effect of the merger on the
economy likely would be positive. In other words, if the gain to producers resulting from
the cost savings and other efficiency gains likely to be brought about by the merger were
greater than the loss to society attributed to the anti-competitive effects, the Tribunal
would not
issue an order in respect of the merger. In this very complicated
analysis, wealth transfers from consumers to producers are treated as neutral, because
they have no bearing on the aggregate level of wealth in the economy. [Paul Crampton,
Davies, Ward, Phillips & Vineberg, 65:11:55]
I have submitted for consideration a one-month initial
review followed by a four-month timeframe. If, after the first month, the Bureau does not
go into a full-scale investigative mode, the merger is cleared. If they do go into that
mode, then there is a fixed period
of four months
to complete the
Bureaus investigation. [Calvin Goldman, Davies, Ward & Beck, 59:09:20] |
Data submitted to the Committee provides evidence of the second part of the claim. The Mergers Branch at the Bureau averaged 38 full-time equivalent person-years in the early 1990s, but has gradually increased to 57 in 2000-2001. Therefore, the Bureaus Mergers Branch has grown by just less than 50% over the employment levels of the early 1990s, which is significantly below the merger filings growth rate of more than 85% in the same period. 29 Moreover, Table 7.2 indicates that the complexity of mergers that the Bureau has had to review is also increasing. Complex mergers and very complex mergers, which are increasingly resource intensive, have augmented their respective shares in the past four years by 4% each. Although non-complex mergers make up the vast majority of cases under review (between 80-90%), their share of total reviews undertaken by the Bureau has declined substantially in the past four years. This trend, the Bureau claims, is due largely to globalization and the inherent complexities associated with multi-jurisdictional cases. |
I recommended earlier that
in the area of merger review consideration be given to trying to define the time periods
with statutory certainty so that business persons engaged in transactions, third parties
interested in transactions and making submissions to the Bureau,
know there are
fixed time periods, as opposed to the current service standard guidelines
This would
promote certainty. [Calvin Goldman,
Davies, Ward & Beck, 59:09:15]
It
will be interesting, now that this merger wave is sort of down, to see how resources are
reallocated. As a result of that, it is certainly true that the other areas of the
organization, such as the civil reviewable practices areas and conspiracy, are not nearly
as well funded relative to other international comparisons. [Margaret Sanderson,
Charles River Associates, 59:11:20] |
29 | Competition Bureau Merger Branch, Merger Review Performance Report June 2001, 2001. |
The revenue generated from fees related to merger review has been a significant but not a fully compensatory help to the Bureaus budget constraint. The Bureau estimates that revenues from pre-merger notification, advance ruling certificates and advisory opinions will be in excess of $8.4 million in 2000-2001, $7.5 million of which will be available to the Bureau. Any fees the Bureau receives in excess of $7.5 million will be credited to the governments Consolidated Revenue Fund. Given that the direct costs of merger review is estimated to be $9.5 million for 2000-2001, merger review revenues clearly fall short of cost recovery. In 1997, along with fees for certain services, the Bureau established and committed itself to meet a series of service standards when reviewing mergers. These standards are: non-complex mergers, 14 days; complex mergers, 10 weeks; and very complex, 5 months. Although the Bureau has, in a given year, met these targets 100% of the time, its performance level has varied without trend since 1997. In fiscal year 2000-2001, the Bureau met the three targets 95.7%, 92.5% and 100% of the time, respectively. The average and median turnaround times for merger review have at all times been shorter than the established standard. However, in every year since 1997, a relatively small number of merger reviews has fallen well outside the target date. These poor performances appear to be isolated cases that are not the result of systemic failures, but are more likely owing to human error errors probably committed on the part of Bureau staff and merging parties. This performance and the targeted standards, the Committee finds, are reasonable. Although there were complaints about the merger review process made to the Committee, stakeholders had not complained about this aspect. |
[T]he Bureaus workload over the past few years
has greatly increased. Unfortunately, our resources have not kept pace ... In a recent
survey involving five comparable competition authorities, our Bureau had the second-lowest
level of funding on a per-capita basis. Our demands continue to grow, largely due to
globalization and our increased mandate. Ten years ago, the great majority of cases
examined by the Bureau were domestic in nature. Today, not only are there more cases, but
a very large number of them have an international dimension. This is demonstrated by the
increasing number of multi-jurisdictional mergers and international cartels. [Gaston
Jorré, Competition Bureau, 64:09:10] |
The Committee believes that the routine merger review procedures of the Bureau are not the cause of selected protracted merger reviews of which people complain. These reviews bog down only when the Commissioner has unresolved issues with the merger (as proposed) and intense negotiation begins for restructuring the merger proposal or when seeking a consent order, or where a contested Tribunal proceeding is going to be launched. As a consequence, the Committee sees no benefit in enshrining strict deadlines for merger review in the Act, as some commentators have suggested. Indeed, the Committee sees more harm than good coming from such Act-imposed deadlines. Given an inviolable deadline, the Bureau would be forced to work more intensively on cases that are likely to run into difficulty and breach the deadline, sacrificing resources in other reviews and therefore delaying less problematic mergers. In effect, strict or Act-imposed deadlines will compress the time distribution of completed reviews, but only at the expense of higher average turnaround times. The combination of an unexpected and uncontrollable merger review workload, growing at rates in excess of that of staffing, with that of quick turnaround times provided by the Bureau is a situation that lends itself to the perception that vigorous enforcement of the Act may have been sacrificed. The Committee will investigate. Table 7.3 provides the Bureaus statistical record of merger enforcement under the Competition Act. 30 The Bureaus entire enforcement record over the 1986-2000 timeframe is included, but the data is broken down into three four-year periods to look for trends in the statistics while overcoming a small numbers problem from which the data suffers. What is clear from the statistical record is that the past four years has involved almost as many merger examinations by the Bureau than that of the previous two four-year periods. Very little else can be discerned with such a high degree of confidence. |
From the Competition
Bureaus perspective, it has limited resources
the Bureau is in fact fairly
strapped when it comes to resources, so it has to make responsible decisions as to how it
deploys those resources. It currently has case-screening criteria that would bias its
decisions in favour of bringing cases that have a broader economic impact. [Paul
Crampton, Davies, Ward, Phillips & Vineberg, 65:10:10] From the Competition Bureaus perspective, it has limited resources
the Bureau is in fact fairly strapped when it comes to resources, so it has to make
responsible decisions as to how it deploys those resources. It currently has
case-screening criteria that would bias its decisions in favour of bringing cases that
have a broader economic impact. [Paul Crampton, Davies, Ward, Phillips &
Vineberg, 65:10:10] From the Competition Bureaus perspective, it has
limited resources
the Bureau is in fact fairly strapped when it comes to resources,
so it has to make responsible decisions as to how it deploys those resources. It currently
has case-screening criteria that would bias its decisions in favour of bringing cases that
have a broader economic impact. [Paul Crampton, Davies, Ward, Phillips &
Vineberg, 65:10:10] |
30 | Data from fiscal year 2000-2001 does not include asset securitizations and is, therefore, not directly comparable. |
The Committee will begin its investigation by considering the perennial complaint that a contested case at the Tribunal is expensive and becoming more so. As such, one would think that the Bureau and the parties to a merger proposal would both shy away from contested proceedings and seek alternative solutions with greater frequency as the cost of a contested case rises. Although the Committee recognizes that there may be other explanations for a trend to fewer contested merger cases particularly when we introduce qualitative information into the analysis the data, while limited, tends to (indirectly) confirm this complaint. Four contested cases of 1,614 merger examinations were taken to the Tribunal for resolution in the two four-year periods starting in 1988 and ending in 1996. Given 1,492 merger investigations and similar vigorous enforcement, one would have expected four contested cases would have gone to the Tribunal in the 1996-2000 period; however, there were only two such cases. Therefore, the behaviours of the Commissioner and prospective merging parties suggest that contested Tribunal cases are becoming more expensive. The vast majority of mergers pose no threat, or raises no issue, under the Competition Act. Donald G. McFetridge reports that about 1.6% of all publicly reported mergers (7.5% of those examined) between 1986 and 1994 raised an issue under the Act.31 According to the data in Table 7.3, the number of issues raised in merger cases has further declined in the latter half of the 1990s. When one subtracts mergers in which monitoring was the chosen enforcement response by the Commissioner because they were never later challenged or brought back under investigation the number of mergers that raised an issue under the Act has average only 2% of examinations undertaken by the Bureau. |
Virtually all the cases
that have been brought in the 15-year period since the Tribunal was created and the merger
provisions were decriminalized have involved mergers that had already been consummated. At
that point the merging parties had every incentive to hunker down and fight. By contrast,
business people invariably have no appetite whatsoever to become involved in contested
proceedings where their transaction has not yet been consummated. [Paul Crampton,
Davies, Ward, Phillips & Vineberg 65:09:55]
[W]e can review any merger, no matter what the size.
Where size comes in is whether you have to notify us.
And I guess
its
a trade-off
if the world were cost-free, it would be nice to look at every merger
and have notification. But given the costs imposed, there has to be some level before you
create a notification process, and thats why there is a threshold for notification.[Gaston
Jorré, Competition Bureau, 64:09:30] |
31 | Donald G. McFetridge, Competition Policy Issues, Research Paper Prepared for the Task Force on the Future of the Canadian Financial Services Sector, September 1998, p. 11. |
The Committee finds it rather curious that, except for contested proceedings, all enforcement responses fell out of favour with the Commissioner (then the Director) in the mid-1990s. However, except for monitoring, all other enforcement responses, such as pre- and post-closing restructuring/undertakings and consent orders, have come back into favour. Moreover, what the Committee finds disturbing is that the number of mergers abandoned by their proponents as a result of the position taken by the Commissioner has declined substantially over the late 1990s. For example, 18 merger proposals were abandoned by their proponents of 1,614 merger examinations undertaken by the Bureau in the two four-year periods starting in 1988 and ending in 1996. Given 1,492 merger investigations and similar vigorous enforcement by the Commissioner, one would have expected about the same number of abandonments, 18, in the 1996-2000 period; however, there were only 4 such abandonments; less than one-quarter of what would reasonably be expected. To the Committee the data suggest one of three explanations: (1) mergers have become less problematic from a competition perspective; (2) the business community at large has in the past five years come to realize that the Commissioner is a vigorous enforcer of his Act and has increasingly acquiesced to other restrictive undertakings imposed by him/her as a means of realizing their mergers; or (3) the business community has in the past five years come to realize that the Commissioners budget is insufficient to vigorously enforce his Act and that he must acquiesce to the merging parties by seeking other non-vigorous merger enforcement methods than that of contesting them under a costly Tribunal proceedings. |
Without qualitative information on these mergers, the Committee cannot draw definitive conclusions. However, the Committee fears that the third explanation is more likely correct and, at least in part, explains the fewer merger proposal abandonments. Somewhat paradoxically, the lack of information published on mergers that the Commissioner did not oppose as a means of protecting private and strategic market information from being made public may be providing more protection, in terms of accountability, to the Commissioner a state of affairs that the competition law community has long complained about. In any event, vigorous enforcement of the merger review provisions can be accomplished by providing the Bureau with adequate resources and allowing it to exercise greater selectivity in the review of mergers that are likely to pose a competition issue recommendations that this Committee advocates. The claim that the Bureau receives insufficient funding for optimal enforcement of the Act, in particular mergers, is not new. In fact, the competition law community has made the Committee aware of this fact since it undertook its study of the Competition Act and its publishing of the Interim Report. The desire for a more complete evaluation that would consider other consequential impacts on enforcement has held the Committee from venturing beyond the call for more resources to be allocated to the Bureau. Given the concern raised in the preceding section, the Committee is now prepared to evaluate specific proposals to raise the merger review thresholds as a way of focusing scarce resources on the larger merger reviews and the enforcement of other aspects of the Act. |
Its not just the
filing fee. When you notify, you have to retain counsel, you have to provide the
information. You need a good adviser.[Gaston Jorré, |
Since the adoption of the Competition Act in 1986, the parties to any significant merger that is, a merger of a certain size as set out in the Act are required to notify the Commissioner before closing the transaction. Although all proposed mergers may be reviewed by the Commissioner, only those mergers (i.e., asset or share acquisitions) involving more than $35 million in gross revenue from sales per annum in or from Canada, or involving more than $400 million in combined assets or sales (including affiliates) in Canada, must notify the Commissioner of the proposed transaction. The transactions threshold for amalgamations is $70 million. Both the gross sales and combined asset thresholds have remained unchanged since 1986.Between 1986 and 2001, inflation of more than 40% (as measured by the consumer price index or CPI) has occurred. Consequently, the $35 million and $400 million thresholds have captured many more mergers than Parliament had intended when the Act was adopted. Indeed, the possible over-inclusiveness of mergers that must automatically undergo review may have been a constraint on optimal enforcement of the Act the Bureau suggests that the gross-revenue-from-sales threshold of $35 million has been particularly binding. In other words, some resources currently devoted to merger review may be more effectively allocated to other activities, either to the review of larger mergers or to the enforcement of other provisions of the Act.The Bureau performed a special request for the Committee that indicates that approximately one in ten mergers examined by its Mergers Branch in the past year fell within the $35 to $50 million transactions range. This statistic, one in ten, suggests that raising the transactions threshold to $50 million would reduce the total number of merger filings by about 40 per year. Unfortunately, we were unable to find out how many of these one-in-ten mergers posed an issue under the Act. Nevertheless, given the deficiency in filing revenues to cover the direct costs of merger review and the Committees belief that there are more pressing needs for enforcement of other activities, we believe that it is best to raise the $35 million transactions threshold to $50 million. The Committee, therefore, recommends: |
One thing that would
help
is the elevation of the thresholds to align them with the economic value of
the threshold as it was when it first came in, in 1988. In 1988 a $35 million threshold on
the transaction size was put in place.
In the meantime, the value of the dollar has
eroded by more than a third, and if we were to make that adjustment today, I think it
would release from the system, from the review, maybe 40% of the cases they now deal with,
and would enable more people to be freed up to do other things. [Tim Kennish, Osler,
Hoskin & Harcourt, 59:09:25]
|
Furthermore, the Committee believes there is merit in formalizing such considerations and, therefore, recommends:
Section 96 of the Competition Act sets Canadas competition legislation apart from those of other countries. This section states that: The Tribunal shall not make an order if the merger brings about gains in efficiencies that are greater than, and will offset, the effects of any prevention or lessening of competition; this has been interpreted by some as being consistent with what is known as the total surplus standard. The Act also goes to considerable lengths to explain both what should and should not be included as a gain in efficiency. For example, the Act states that the gains in efficiency to be considered are those that would not likely be attained if an order were made in respect of the merger; that is, they must be merger specific. This implies that if the efficiencies could be realized in a manner that generates less anticompetitive harm than that created by the merger, then the efficiencies would not be ascribed to the merger. For example, efficiencies that could occur through internal growth or unilateral rationalization would not be ascribed to the merger. Alternatively, there may exist other cooperative means of achieving the efficiencies, such as joint ventures or a restructured merger, which would create lesser anticompetitive effects. Additionally, the efficiencies must be real and not just pecuniary; that is, the merger must bring about a real savings in resources and must not stem from greater bargaining or purchasing power that is essentially redistributive among members of society. |
There are two thresholds. Theres the
transaction size and theres the party size. And we think it would be appropriate to
increase the transaction size threshold, which currently is $35 million. The party-size
threshold, which is $400 million, is much higher and we see increasing the first, but not
the latter, roughly in line with inflation for the period since the Act came in, which
takes you to about $50 million.[Gaston Jorré, Competition Bureau, 64:09:30] But in looking at it historically, in
countries that have had strong competition laws, like the U.S., and countries that had
very weak competition laws, like Japan, they found that they didnt end up with very
productive and efficient economies when they didnt foster competition and make sure
those efficiencies, that productivity and efficiency, were there. So when the cases are
looked at, its not just on the basis of the consumer or the small business alone,
but the Canadian economy and what benefits consumers as a whole.[Robert Russell,
Borden, Ladner & Gervais, 65:10:15] The analysis of
efficiencies in competition law in this country is in a state of disarray, to say the
least. Weve had 15 years or more of toing and froing on it, and still dont
know if we have anything we can work with. So if youre going to go for the section
45 reform
[focus on] what constitutes the civil test. [Donald McFetridge,
Carleton University, 59:10:05] |
Canada is the only country known to have a competition legislation that requires the efficiencies likely to be produced by a merger to be weighed against the likely anticompetitive effects of the merger. This approach occupies the middle ground between the European Union approach, whereby the merging parties are invited to make claim to efficiencies that the Merger Task Force will consider (which introduces lobbying into the mix), and the U.S. approach, which requires efficiency gains to be so great that prices will not rise as a result of the proposed merger (the so-called price standard). In retrospect, this is not an unreasonable approach and, in fact, may be a strategically sound one given Canadas relatively smaller and open market economy. Although this legislative defence is unique among the industrialized countries of the world, its 15-year history has not been very hospitable to merger proponents. The Commissioner has not even once found the efficiency gains to a merger proposal sufficient to offset any lessening of substantial competition. This behaviour contrasts sharply with the Commissioners findings of efficiency gains on many occasions pertaining to exclusive dealing and tied selling cases. Furthermore, in this same 15-year period, the Tribunal has only once decided (Superior Propane) and twice commented on efficiency gains (Imperial Oil and Hillsdown). The elucidations, however, have been confusing to say the least. Just when the Tribunal has come to agree with the Bureaus guidelines on the treatment of efficiencies according to the total surplus standard (Superior Propane), the Bureau abandoned its guidelines. To further confuse the issue, the Federal Court weighed in and partially overturned the Tribunals decision in favour of expanding the strictly quantitative analysis of the total surplus standard to include redistributional and other qualitative effects of the merger, while neither advocating the consumer surplus standard or the American price standard approach. This Court direction had the consequence of opening the door to the Commissioner, as well as to the lone dissenting Trial judge sitting on the Superior Propane case, to advocate the consumer surplus standard.32 Sensing that the latter standard would render section 96 virtually ineffective, the majority opinion of the Tribunal panel chose to supplement the total surplus standard with a calculation of what is described as the adverse social effects of the merger, i.e., the wealth redistributed from poor Canadian consumers to the shareholders of the merging parties. |
Within the merger review
guidelines theres a part
about efficiencies which was written many years ago
before Superior Propane. We have, in effect, withdrawn it. Weve said that
theyve now been superseded by the Court of Appeal on Superior Propane and at some
point once the Superior Propane case is finished were going to have to re-write them
because clearly theyre not, after this litigation, a reliable guide.[Gaston
Jorré, Competition Bureau, 64:10:00] |
32 | The consumer surplus standard weighs the gains in efficiencies against the so-called deadweight loss arising from the merger, as does the total surplus standard, as well as the wealth transferred from consumers to the shareholders of the merging companies. So the consumer surplus standard is a more restrictive test than is the total surplus standard. |
The Tribunals decision in Superior Propane may or may not be satisfactory; it is not clear if such precise calculations of the wealth redistributed from poor consumers to the shareholders of producers will be possible in future cases. Moreover, so many different interpretations of Parliaments intentions when it stated that the effects of a merger that would prevent or lessen competition must be weighed against the gains in efficiency suggest that more expert study is required. 33 Accordingly, the Committee recommends:
|
In my view, the guidance given by that Federal Court of Appeal decision is not adequate to this task. broadly speaking it says the Tribunal, in considering weight given to efficiencies, should apply a flexible approach, not restricted to a total surplus approach It takes account of diverse factors, such as the effects on small business, the possibility of creating monopolies, and perhaps income-distribution effects. [T]his Federal Court of Appeal decision is quite flawed in some respects. I also think it doesnt, whether flawed or not, give a good guide to the future conduct of competition policy. I also believe theres a danger that Canada could move from a position of being more supportive of efficiency claims in merger review than the United States to a position where we could be less supportive of efficiency claims than the Americans. [Roger Ware, Queens University, 65:11:30 |
33 | In Superior Propane, the Tribunal also heard testimony in favour of the price standard, the U.S.-modified price standard, and Professor Townleys balancing weights approach. |