:
I call this meeting to order. Welcome to meeting number 153 of the Standing Committee on Finance.
Today's meeting is taking place in a hybrid format. All witnesses have completed the required connection tests in advance of the meeting. I'd like to remind participants of the following points.
Please wait until I recognize you by name before speaking. All comments should be addressed through the chair. Members, please raise your hand if you wish to speak, whether you're participating in person or via Zoom. The clerk and I will manage the speaking order as best we can.
Pursuant to Standing Order 108(2) and the motion adopted by the committee on June 13, 2024, the committee is resuming its study of the changes to capital gains and corresponding measures announced in budget 2024.
I would like to welcome our witnesses. With us today, as an individual, we have an adjunct professor of health policy at Simon Fraser University, Professor Steven Lewis. He is joining us via video conference. From the Canadian Cattle Association, we have the senior director of government relations and public affairs, Ms. Jennifer Babcock, as well as officer at large Jack Chaffe. From Canadians for Tax Fairness, we have Katrina Miller, who's the executive director there. From the Office of the Parliamentary Budget Officer, we have the Parliamentary Budget Officer with us, Yves Giroux. Joining Mr. Giroux is the director of budgetary analysis, Govindadeva Bernier.
You'll have up to five minutes to make your opening remarks. Then we'll proceed to the rounds of questions from the members.
Members, we are having some technical challenges with Kim Moody, who's also here as an individual. We're trying to fix those, so we'll put him at the end right now. Hopefully those challenges will be rectified.
I guess there are some connection issues with Katrina Miller for Canadians for Tax Fairness. She is trying to find a piece that will work with her computer or system, so that she's able to connect with us. Hopefully that happens.
With that, we're going to start with Steven Lewis, please, for up to five minutes.
:
Thank you, Mr. Chair. Thank you for this opportunity to present to the committee.
I'm a health policy analyst and health researcher. I have listened to two previous committee sessions and will try to avoid repeating arguments ably made before.
I will focus on how the capital gains inclusion rate changes will and will not affect self-employed incorporated professionals, such as doctors and independent consultants like me. The changes will cost us some money, as they should. I will explain why and address some of the claims about the adverse effects of the changes.
First, tax regimes are grounded in, and should reflect, explicit values. The changes are designed to raise revenues, and, importantly, to make the tax system fairer. They will modestly reduce income and wealth disparities by taking more money from higher-income people. The math is simple. If you oppose the changes, you oppose reducing income disparities, at least by this measure. I would emphasize how important it is for participants in these policy debates to disclose their values transparently.
Second, all of us should avoid overstating the alleged impact of any single and relatively modest tax policy change. If any such measure could on its own either exacerbate or solve any of Canada's inequality, housing, productivity, infrastructure, innovation or other problems, there would be documented evidence by now. The tax code remains largely intact and still privileges people like me.
Capital gains remain more lightly taxed than earned income. For professionals, these gains accrue mainly from conventional investments. Few of us are venture capitalists rolling the dice on game-changing innovations. Our incentives are unchanged, and our actual tax rates will remain considerably lower than nominal rates. The system remains less progressive, in fact, than it is on paper.
Third, the measure, though positive, will not do much to address Canada's serious wealth concentration problem. The tax system still makes it easier for me to grow my wealth than an ordinary working person. I can keep some profits in my company indefinitely and pay only 10% to 12% off the top, depending on the province. I can invest the remainder, and until these assets are sold, their value grows untaxed. I can smooth out income over a number of years to reduce my annual tax bill. Some of my income will still be taxed lower than the income of a wage earner with no such options and predictably fewer capital gains.
Fourth, it has been argued that retained earnings in corporations are the retirement plans for professionals who don't have an employer or state-funded pension. Any prudent doctor or consultant like me has a powerful incentive to take enough money out of the company in income to maximize their annual RRSP contribution, currently about $32,000. The RRSP grows tax free until money is withdrawn and also generates about a $15,000 annual income tax refund. It is likewise simple common sense to maximize annual TFSA contributions. With conservative rates of return, over 30 to 35 years, these funds grow to several million dollars.
Fifth, if it is determined that, say, family physician incomes are too low to attract and retain full-time practitioners, the solution is to give them more money. For example, the B.C. government gave them a 54% increase as part of its November 2022 contract with Doctors of B.C. The tax system is a clumsy instrument for addressing a very particular problem.
Sixth, and perhaps most importantly, a fair tax system that eliminates some advantages for people like me and confers new benefits on lower-income people will do more to improve the health of the population than billions of new dollars poured into health care. Put simply, health status is better in countries with less income and wealth inequality. More equitable tax policy is excellent health policy.
That is why I support the capital gains tax policy changes, but they should just be the beginning of other changes that create more security and opportunities for lower-income people to realize their potential, increase their productivity, accumulate wealth and improve their health.
Thank you.
:
Thank you for this opportunity to present on behalf of the Canadian Cattle Association, or CCA, in your study on changes to the capital gains measures as announced in budget 2024.
My name is Jack Chaffe. I am the co-chair of domestic agriculture with CCA and past president of the Beef Farmers of Ontario. Along with my family, I own and operate a beef feedlot in southwestern Ontario.
CCA is the national organization representing Canada's 60,000 beef producers. The Canadian beef cattle industry is a significant driver of our economy and a global leader in sustainability, contributing $21.8 billion to Canada's GDP and supporting approximately 350,000 full-time equivalent jobs. A prosperous and thriving beef industry generates considerable economic, environmental and social opportunities and benefits to Canada.
CCA has been extensively engaged in discussions on changes to the capital gains since it was first announced last spring in the federal budget. Before we get into the specific measures announced, I need to emphasize that the current capital gains measure that includes intergenerational transfers of beef operations within families is critical. CCA is concerned that the recent changes to the capital gains tax will increase the requirement to sell off pieces of farms when they change hands. We need to ensure that the federal government does not jeopardize the current tax policy that allows the intergenerational transfer of beef operations within families.
In general, the lack of meaningful consultation time in advance of the announced changes is concerning. Beef producers have not had time to assess the changes and how they will impact their family operations. Each operation is unique. It has been difficult to quantify the changes in our sector on the whole without the proper consultation time.
We need to consider the impacts of the inclusion rate despite the changes announced on August 12. While we were pleased to see the changes to lifetime exemptions, other amendments to the measures are counter to those announced under Bill and its amendments in budget 2023. By increasing the capital gains inclusion rate, the federal government risks weakening the provisions under Bill C-208 that facilitate smoother intergenerational farm transfers to those younger producers.
The majority of Canadian farms operate under a family operation, but each farm is unique in its operational structure. To address the vast differences between those structures, producers need greater clarity regarding the changes between August 12 and those announced in budget 2024. The changes announced in the budget were done without consultation, which creates confusion for farmers whose operations are built on years of tax advice.
In addition to producers, tax advisers and accountants also require more time to assess the changes and how they will affect the families across Canada. Specifically, there are unanswered questions about whether farms qualify under the Canadian entrepreneurs' incentive, as an example. Although we are able to receive tax advice from our advisers, we need more guidance and clarification from the federal government on who qualifies for those incentives.
Regarding the timing of the proposal, the consultation period lasted only three weeks and during a busy time for the farmers. We therefore need more time to accurately analyze the impacts to our producers across Canada. Our sector is at risk of losing a significant portion of the workforce, as farmers may retire without viable succession plans. This also places Canada's rural economy at risk of declining. We need to ensure that government policies do not unintentionally contribute to the decline of agricultural production in Canada.
Thank you for your time. I would be happy to answer any questions that may come.
:
Good afternoon, committee members.
My name is Kim Moody. I'm a fellow of the chartered accountants of Alberta. I have a very long history of serving the Canadian tax profession with a variety of significant leadership positions. I'm also a prolific writer and speaker on taxation matters, including writing a weekly column in the Financial Post.
Today, I'd like to briefly comment on three key matters regarding these proposals. The first is the policy underpinning the capital gains inclusion rate increase. Canada has a long and interesting history on the taxation of capital gains, and one can have respectful debates on whether the inclusion rate for capital gains should be 50%, two-thirds, 75% or even 100%. Given Canada's historical debate and treatment on this, put me on record as an advocate for a low inclusion rate, like 50%, since that lower inclusion rate provides incentive and acknowledgement of a key issue that most people experience when they originally invest capital to generate such gains. That key differentiator is risk.
It takes guts to buy land, to build a building and to rent it out, to buy a farm, to start a business or to buy a business. Most Canadians are not wired to accept that risk, so why is this important?
Members of the committee, thank you for the invitation to appear before you today. We are pleased to discuss our analysis related to your study of the changes to the capital gains inclusion rate and corresponding measures announced in budget 2024.
With me today I have Mr. Govindadeva Bernier, director of budgetary analysis.
Consistent with the Parliamentary Budget Officer's mandate to provide independent, non-partisan analysis to Parliament, my office released our cost estimate on August 1.
[English]
As you are aware, budget 2024 introduced an increase in the capital gains inclusion rate from one-half to two-thirds for corporations and trusts, and from—
I think we're still working on Mr. Moody, so that's still a work-in-progress, and the same thing for Ms. Katrina Miller.
We are now going to move to members' questions. If we do rectify those connection issues, then we will bring them back to give their statements or to finish off their statements, and then get back to members' questions.
Right now, we're starting with the first round. Each party will have up to six minutes to ask questions.
We're beginning with MP Morantz for the first six minutes.
:
It's better to have a conversation, Mr. Chair, but perhaps some other time.
In any event, Mr. Moody has made some excellent points and criticisms of the move by the government to increase the inclusion rate, so hopefully we'll be able to get him on before the end of the meeting so that he can tell my Liberal colleagues on the committee why it's such a bad idea.
Now, Mr. Chaffe, I listened to your comments with interest. When somebody enters the agricultural industry, whether it's to farm, to raise cattle or to raise hogs for the pork industry, when they make that investment, they're taking a risk—are they not?
I'm going to direct my questions to Mr. Lewis.
Welcome to committee. Thank you for following this committee for the last number of meetings.
I want to just comment on a couple of the points you made in your opening comments, starting with the impact of capital gains on income inequality and tax inequality and income disparity in the country. Something we've fallen into, I think, in this committee and in some of the conversations around the capital gains adjustment is really overstating the impact that this very modest tax change is having.
With that in mind, some professionals—and you have probably heard this in other testimony or other meetings here—incorporate to obtain generous tax and liability benefits. Those could be doctors, plumbers or certainly, as you have indicated, independent consultants. We've heard from some MPs that these changes will kill economic growth and job creation. What is your response to this?
I know you referenced some of this very clearly in your opening comments, but I'd like you to restate it, if you wouldn't mind, for the record.
:
I see no mechanism whereby that tax change will have any impact on job creation. I will lose money. I will pay some more money because of this. None of my incentives have changed. They're still there. If I want to make more money, I will work harder to make more money. This capital gains inclusion increase will essentially add about a third—from 25% to say 33%—of what I will pay on money that is gained through capital gains by the retained earnings in my company. It will not affect any decision about whether I hire somebody or a research assistant or something, because I would be spiting myself to let it affect those decisions.
As far as investments in new kinds of industries go, what happens to our money? In other words, what happens to the wealth that people like me accumulate in our companies? Maybe one or two people put their money in local entrepreneurs and take a flyer on a daring investment, but that's not what most of us do. We buy stocks, bond securities and standard kinds of investments.
If we make money on those, the money we make on those is still taxed less than the money we make by the sweat of our brow working, and it's the same for salaried people. In the case of self-employed professionals with private corporations, frankly, I don't think anything we do has anything to do with creating new jobs. I just don't think that's how it works.
I realize that you referenced some of this in your opening comments, but I'd like to give you an opportunity to go a little deeper. We know that in Canada 100% of Canadian employment income is subject to tax, whereas 50% of capital gains, up to $250,000, was included in that income. Now, with the changes we're proposing, we're bumping this up to two-thirds of any capital gains exceeding $250,000.
Could you comment on who has benefited from this preferential treatment of capital gains in Canada and then give us any other information to try to dispel some of the comments that have been made?
:
In general, the people who benefit from this favourable treatment are people who have enough money to invest in securities, land and other kinds of investments, or, frankly, in cottages and lakefront property that has a chance of growing. A lot of that, again, is not very risky.
I actually also have family land in southeastern Saskatchewan. I know Mr. Moody will address this later. It is not a risky proposition to have farmland in Canada. It's been going up at an enormous rate—10%, 12%, 15% or 20% a year—for many years in my province, and this creates enormous capital gains. If you're only taxed on half of that, those people who have land will get richer quicker.
The long and the short of it is, on a personal level—never mind if you have a corporation—if you have enough invested that you make $250,000 a year more in capital gains, you're getting an incredible bargain with the exemption. The whole bargain you had before.... If you made a million dollars in capital gains by investing in crypto, then you would be taxed at a maximum of 25%. Now that break is reduced, but you still have $250,000 of capital gain on which you will pay a maximum of 25%, which is a tremendous tax advantage.
While none of us celebrates having to pay more money, this is not a particularly enormous blow to your income prospects. It will be some, but to say that this is somehow reducing people to a precarious state, if you're a doctor, a lawyer or a consultant like me, strikes me as a major overstatement.
:
I'm here to talk about how the changes to capital gains taxation can help move us toward a more equitable and affordable society.
I'll be focusing my comments on recent research that we've done regarding how large corporations, particularly those in the finance and real estate sectors, are increasingly cashing in on capital gains because of this tax break and why allowing them to do so is actually harming our path toward an affordable Canada.
We've appeared in front of this committee before to present our research on how the profit margins amongst corporations across many sectors have been growing over the years—quite astoundingly during the pandemic and after the pandemic. During that time, their productive investment has basically stalled out. At the same time, their overall tax rate has fallen. That's because of tax breaks like capital gains and the fact that they're taking greater advantage of those tax breaks, as well as avoidance measures that they're putting into place.
In fact, we've shown that in 2022, Canada missed out on $30 billion of public revenue that could have gone directly to investments in health care, education and housing, which are the kinds of investments that make life more affordable for your average Canadian family.
Today, I'm here to present information from a report we just released yesterday, in fact, about how capital gains and the tax breaks associated with them are hurting our attempts to make housing more affordable in Canada.
In 2023, average rents rose by 8%, while our wages rose an average of 5%. During that time, Canada's real estate sector walked away with $50 billion in profits. That's 40% higher than their prepandemic record.
Financialized landlords—those are real estate investment trusts or private equity funds—are playing an ever-greater role in our housing market. The sector now owns about one-quarter of all purpose-built rental stock. They are the majority purchaser for these properties on the market right now. These financial companies seek out assets that offer the greatest returns. Our capital gains tax break has sweetened the pot considerably for them.
Since the Chrétien government lowered the inclusion rate for capital from 75% to 50% in 2000, we've seen an 860% increase in profit made through capital gains in the real estate sector. These companies are quite clear in their publicly available financial documents that their motivation is to increase rents as much as the market will bear in order to increase ongoing returns and also the value of the property at point of sale. As I mentioned, asset sales are becoming an increasing source of profit.
In 2022 alone, Canada's largest seven residential REITs distributed $100 million of tax-free capital gains directly to investors. In this context, the government's move to increase the inclusion rate to two-thirds is obviously welcomed.
However, the tax incentive for capital gains still remains under these rules. There's still a third that remains tax free. Combine that with the continued corporate tax breaks that we have for REITs in our system and our tax system is still adding fuel to the growing financialization of housing and, with it, to our rental affordability crisis.
Therefore, the Canadians for Tax Fairness recommends a full inclusion of inflation-adjusted capital gains in taxable income, especially for the finance, insurance and real estate sectors. These large corporations should not get tax breaks for owning land that appreciates in value without productive investment into that property.
In addition, the government should rescind the corporate tax breaks for REITs, acknowledging that their role in our housing market is driving, to some extent, our rental affordability crisis. Removing the tax breaks that make it so attractive for financial firms to buy up rental housing, use it as an asset instead of treating it as a home and raise rent simply to increase the asset's value is an important step to making housing affordable in Canada.
The public revenue that we can gain from removing these harmful tax breaks, which will be well over $1 billion annually, could be directly funnelled into building the non-market housing that Canada needs right now in order to make our overall housing stock more affordable.
That's it for my comments at this moment. I look forward to your questions.
Greetings to all my colleagues.
I would like to thank all the witnesses for joining us today, and for their very useful presentations.
Obviously, we don't yet have the text of the bill. There was a second notice of ways and means motion yesterday, which we are currently considering. I look forward to seeing the bill so that we can analyze the soundness of this proposed tax policy.
Currently, millionaires and billionaires have a lower tax rate than the middle class in general. That must be corrected; it's a matter of tax fairness. We fully agree on that principle. However, we have many concerns about small-scale savers in the middle class who could be affected by the measure when they are not the ones being targeted. Let's take the example of a middle-class person who decides, for retirement income, to buy a multiplex and resell it when they retire. That person could be affected by this measure, whereas people in the middle class are not the ones being targeted.
My questions are for Mr. Giroux and Mr. Bernier.
I look forward to seeing your next study, which you presented briefly. I want you to know that I am particularly concerned about people who will declare a gain only on an ad hoc basis, as you said. The Corporation des propriétaires immobiliers du Québec, or CORPIQ, tells us that 82% of triplex, quadruplex or quintuplex owners are in Quebec. So we would like special attention to be paid to that. We would also like you to provide, in the breakdown of your data, the cases that involve the sale of a secondary residence or an estate.
First of all, Mr. Giroux and Mr. Bernier, have you had time to look at the new notice of ways and means motion? If so, were there any elements that drew your attention, in terms of the ways and means motion that was passed last June?
:
Good afternoon, committee members.
My name is Kim Moody. I'm a fellow of the Chartered Professional Accountants of Alberta and the founder of Moodys Tax and Moodys Private Client, a significant boutique advisory firm in Canada. I have a very long history of serving the Canadian tax profession with a variety of significant leadership positions. I'm also a prolific writer and speaker on taxation matters, including writing a weekly column on taxation for the Financial Post.
Today, I want to talk to you on three key matters regarding these proposals.
The first is the policy underpinning the capital gains inclusion rate proposal. Canada has a long and interesting history on the taxation of capital gains, and one can have a respectful debate on whether the inclusion rate for capital gains should be 50%, two-thirds, 75% or even, as some on this panel have advocated, 100%. However, put me on record as an advocate for a low inclusion rate, like 50%, since that lower inclusion rate provides incentive and acknowledgement of a key issue that most people experience when they originally invest capital to generate such gains.
That key differentiator is risk. It takes guts to buy land, to build a building and to rent it out, to buy a farm or to start or buy a business. Most Canadians are not wired to accept that risk, unlike some who think that investing is risk free. It is not. This is important because the ones who can hang on and make something out of their risky venture usually have spinoff benefits for a large number of Canadians. Canada needs to encourage the creation of more entrepreneurs and investment in our country, and a lower capital gains inclusion rate is one of those policy tools that has historically helped with that.
This proposal is a simple tax grab, no more, no less. At a time when Canada has significant productivity challenges, the last thing we need to do is send signals to Canadians and to others that Canada is not the place to encourage entrepreneurship and/or invest their capital.
The other significant policy concern I have is that individuals are afforded a $250,000 annual threshold at the 50% inclusion rate, whereas most trusts and all corporations are not. That proposal blows a hole in the policy of integration, which has been a core principle of Canadian tax for decades and decades. In other words, taxpayers should be neutral, from a taxation perspective, as to where their investment dollars are placed when comparing various legal alternatives. Now, however, taxpayers will be encouraged to realize capital gains personally so as to be afforded the $250,000 threshold, and this will, of course, cause distortions that are simply not good.
Number two is the disingenuous messaging surrounding this proposal. By now, it is well known that the famous so-called “statistic” that this measure would only apply to 0.13% of Canadians, which appeared in the budget documents, is simply false and disingenuous. It still shocks me that a simple and misleading so-called “statistic” would be put forward by a government to try to justify its proposal.
When faced with criticism on that, the pivot was to say that the increase was necessary to deal with intergenerational fairness. The also advertised a new slogan in a cutesy but misleading video where he called it the “capital gains advantage”. Then, of course, there was the pivoting by the with her famous “higher fences” comment.
These are examples of horrible politics trying to justify poor policy. Like many Canadians, I find it divisive, misleading and disgusting. As I stated earlier, one can have a respectful debate on whether an inclusion rate is a good policy, but to denigrate that subject into divisive politics is disappointing, to say the least.
Third, and last, is the implementation of the proposal. Setting aside my strong dissent to this capital gains increase, I now will consider whether this proposal is well thought out and implemented. It is clear the capital gains inclusion rate proposal in the 2024 budget was half-baked. No draft legislation was available on budget day, with that proposal to be effective roughly 10 weeks later on June 25. On June 10, the imperfect first batch of draft legislation was released and, as expected, was very technically complex.
Given the complexity, this clearly was not enough time to advise Canadians on their affairs, since the effective date would come into effect almost immediately. The second batch was released on August 12, and it's imperfect. Late yesterday, the third batch was released, and of course most Canadians have not had the chance to review it yet.
Canadians should expect detailed draft legislation to accompany significant tax policy changes and proposals. One important fix the government could do would be to redirect some of the huge amount of money that has been allocated to the Canada Revenue Agency in recent years to the Department of Finance's tax legislation division—even a small amount of it to go there—because there are a small number of hard-working bureaucrats in that division who are expected to carry a very heavy load to properly draft this important legislation. Extra resources allocated to them would be a positive step in the right direction.
The second implementation concern is the fact that the only way for Canadian taxpayers to avoid retrospective taxation on their accrued gains up until June 25 was to trigger actual gains on their assets. The government budgeted for Canadians to do this. Think about that for even two seconds. In order to avoid—
:
Sure. I appreciate the question.
We looked at our labour productivity, which is often how we view productivity in developed economies, and how that played out over the longitudinal set of data of our capital gains inclusion rates when they bounced from having no capital gains to 50% and 75%, and back down to 50%. What we found was that there was just absolutely no correlation whatsoever between the rate of capital gains taxation and our productivity.
We looked across a variety of economies across the globe and found the exact same data. Higher capital gains inclusion rates do not correlate with lower productivity.
What we know, from many longitudinal studies—some done by the London School of Economics—is that greater inequity in a society, which comes from tax systems like ours, has a regressive result on society. That, through things like the capital gains tax break, does in fact put a drag on productivity.
Something we would like to see explored in deeper ways in Canada is whether or not our low taxation of corporations and very wealthy people is providing a drag on our productivity right now as a country.
:
Yes, the same mechanisms are available to all Canadians, and, in particular, higher-income Canadians who are able to save more.
The RRSP, of course, is the number one mechanism. As I mentioned in my opening remarks, if you're prudent and you're a physician.... Let's take the average physician in Alberta, who, according to the CMA's own reckoning, will have a pre-tax income of about $240,000. The maximum you need to make the maximum RRSP contribution is in the order of $155,000 to $160,000, I think—maybe a little bit higher.
Anyway, the incentive is to take as much money out of the corporation as is required to make the maximum RRSP contribution. You put in $32,000 a year. It grows tax free until you retire. If you do it every year, you get a $15,000, roughly, tax refund. It only costs you $17,000 to make that $32,000 investment. Do the simple spreadsheet. Over 35 years, at modest rates of return, 6% to 7%—if you bought the Toronto Stock Exchange index, for simplicity—you cannot help but have that grow to millions of dollars.
In the meantime, you still have money left in your corporation, which is lightly taxed as a small business. In Alberta, it would be 9% to 10%. You can invest that any way you want, some of which will generate capital gains, etc.
This is a tremendous tax advantage for an incorporated professional. I have the same incentive.
It sounds like we don't have Mr. Moody. I would like to, if I can, on the record, ensure that the clerk connects with him, so that we can have his full statement entered into evidence. It didn't sound like he had finished his statement. I would have many questions for him if he were available. In fact, I may ask him to expand, based on some of the questions that have come up, if he has additional remarks, so that we don't lose the benefit of his testimony over the interpretation issues.
With that, I'll turn to the Parliamentary Budget Officer. Thank you for being here today.
When you calculate the projected $17 billion over five years, is that just a straight-up calculation based on gains, taking the old rate and expanding the rate on what you would expect to receive?
:
Yes, if you can table that, it would helpful.
Let me go to Mr. Lewis.
In the very beginning of your opening statement, you acknowledged that this change will affect many Canadians, including yourself and many of the thousands, perhaps millions, of Canadians who are self-employed and have a corporation. Particularly the ones with corporations are the ones who do not have the $250,000 exemption. From your own research, do you know how many Canadians you expect...?
You said this will affect many Canadians, and it's your belief that it should. You think these particular Canadians should pay more taxes. I may not agree with you. In fact, I don't agree with you on that point.
However, could you share it with the committee if you have a number or if your own research has pegged how many will be affected by this change?
That's important, because we have been repeatedly told by the government that it's some extraordinary low number of Canadians who will be affected.
The lack of inclusion for at least the $250,000 exemption really does specifically target those who have their small businesses set up legally as corporations. That includes doctors—as you said—consultants, building contractors like plumbers and electricians, physiotherapists and a number of health professionals, owners of shops or small businesses, restaurateurs and bar owners. Maybe I'm missing other categories of people. It's a pretty large group, though.
:
Thank you so much, Mr. Chair.
I want to thank all of our speakers today for their presentations and for being here and being part of this really excellent discussion.
My first question will go to Ms. Miller.
Ms. Miller, often in our discussions about capital gains, we tend to leave out the importance of the programs this increase to the inclusion rate is going to be funding. We forget what we're trying to do. Part of it is the importance of the programs we want to be investing in, as well as tax fairness between generations.
Can you speak to the importance of some of the policies within our social safety net that we want to have lasting changes to? Do you think it's right to ask those who are making a capital gain of over $250,000 in a given year to help fund these important programs?
The other question I will ask is very relevant in my little riding of Davenport in west downtown Toronto.
I have a lot of immigrants, and the largest population I have is actually the Portuguese population. When they first came in the seventies and eighties, many of them ended up buying a second house just because, to be honest, they had trouble finding jobs. What they ended up doing is buying a second house and renting it out.
I know you talked about how it was good for us to be increasing the capital gains inclusion rate because it has the appropriate impact on REITs. How would you respond to someone who came here and invested in additional property to help support their living and ultimately wants to sell it in order to provide a legacy to their kids or grandkids?
My question is for Mr. Giroux.
In an article published today in La Presse, Joël‑Denis Bellavance points out that the ways and means motion was voted on, but that the bill has still not been introduced and therefore could not be passed to date. However, should the government be defeated before implementing legislation is passed, the measure would fall, despite the adoption of the ways and means motion. Joël‑Denis Bellavance mentions that it was senator and economist Clément Ablonczy who recalled a past case where the Conservative government had passed a ways and means motion to raise the gas tax but was defeated 10 days later, so the tax increase was cancelled when Parliament was dissolved.
I would like to hear your thoughts on that, first of all.
I would also like to know what you think of the government's approach: A notice of ways and means motion was moved two weeks before the measure came into force, and now, several months later, no implementing legislation has been introduced. Is that a good way to proceed?
:
If the government were defeated before the bill received royal assent, the measure would obviously no longer apply. The capital gains inclusion rate would therefore be 50% for everyone.
As for the fact that the bill to implement this measure hasn't yet been introduced, and that it was the subject of a notice of ways and means motion separate from the rest of the budget content, this is a bit unusual for such an important measure. I can understand that it's probably technical issues that are still preventing the bill from being introduced. However, given the nature of the measure, we would have expected the legislative drafters at the Department of Finance to have drafted the appropriate amendments and published technical documents much more quickly, rather than what we've seen in recent weeks or months.
In summary, there was the announcement of the budget, then the notice of ways and means motion several weeks later, and then another revised notice. This sequence of events is a bit surprising.
:
Got it. I also want to just quickly ask this.
Mr. Lewis, there are some suggestions that only entrepreneurs take risks and that's how they justify capital gains, but wage earners face the risks of job loss, economic downturns and company restructuring. They risk income instability and things like wage stagnation, reduced hours of benefits, losing funds due to inflation and health and safety risks, which can jeopardize a worker's earning potential.
What do you have to say to those who say that, in trying to put food on the table for their families, only entrepreneurs take risks when they enter the workplace?
You know, just like the capital gains tax hike, it has cascading effects, much like something else. We all know what the carbon tax does. Thank you for being open to taking other questions as well.
I wanted to confirm a few things with you, Mr. Giroux, if you're okay with that. Can you tell us what the total impact on the economy is, the hit to the economy, when we factor in carbon tax one and carbon tax two?
:
I understand. That said, my Conservative colleague raised the issue of the carbon tax. To assess the impact of this tax, we have to assess not only the cost, but also the benefits to society of protecting our environment and reducing financial costs, among other things.
If we assess the financial cost and the benefits in the case of the carbon tax, wouldn't it be appropriate, in the case of an increase in the inclusion rate, to assess not only the costs—people will indeed pay more taxes—but also the positive effect on society? That way, we would really assess the impact of this measure.
It's not as if the money is going to be given to the government and disappear. It's going to be spent on something. The government has set out its intention in the budget with respect to new spending and programs, such as housing.
Wouldn't it be appropriate to evaluate that?
:
That's a good point, and it comes up often.
My office has a mandate to estimate the cost and impact of certain measures. In general, the government is very good at talking about the benefits of its proposals. Where there is often an information asymmetry is when we talk about the costs or repercussions of certain measures. If I were doing cost-benefit analyses, as is sometimes suggested, my office should have a mandate that is considerably different from its current mandate.
Furthermore, it would be difficult to estimate the benefits of a measure such as the capital gains inclusion rate, because it would then have to be determined where the funds would be paid. The government said it would use the funds for certain purposes, but it could have generated revenue in other ways. If we did cost-benefit analyses, it would force us to become policy analysts and to comment on the merits of certain very specific policies.
That is why we only estimate the costs of certain measures. We leave it to parliamentarians to arbitrate and determine the ratio between costs and benefits. For our part, we provide the information on the costs. The government, on the other hand, often provides very good information on the benefits. By putting all that together, legislators—in this case you and your colleagues—are able to make good trade-offs and arrive at good decisions.
:
It won't surprise my committee colleagues where I fall.
I'll take the opportunity to mention that the government just released yesterday a new ways and means motion. I think we're supposed to vote on that tomorrow. There's been no briefing offered to parliamentarians about what's changed in that motion, so perhaps those folks in the finance department might like to make themselves available.
I would put this as an adjacent to Mr. Morantz's motion, about just being a little more rigorous around the changes they're doing and making sure we have the right impact statement.
When the government introduces one ways and means motion in June or late May, and then another one on the same issue without the final draft of legislation but doesn't offer a briefing to parliamentarians about what's changed in that motion.... I think it would just be good practice to offer that to parliamentarians, so they know what's changing and what we're voting on in less than 24 hours.
:
Thank you. I would like the opportunity to speak, Mr. Chair.
Once again, we see the Conservative motion on capital gains being interrupted by the Conservatives. It's unfortunate because there are several Conservatives, as well as other witnesses, here to provide interesting testimony.
Mr. Chair, given that a member of this committee, Mr. Davies, has requested time to review the motion—the motion is quite detailed—I would suggest that we hold a committee meeting to discuss committee business. In that meeting, we can talk about all of the motions that are before us and see where the committee would like to go for the remainder of the fall session.
Given that there are several other studies that have been proposed, that have been on the books for quite some time and that, I think, members would like to get to, and considering that we've already studied several Conservative motions at the finance committee, I would suggest that we proceed in that way.
With respect to the motion that is currently on the floor of your meeting, Mr. Chair, I move to adjourn debate.
(Motion agreed to: yeas 6; nays 5)
:
Good afternoon, Mr. Lewis, at Burnaby Mountain. It's a lovely part of this beautiful country that we live in.
Mr. Lewis, we know that a tax system is designed to raise revenue to pay for services that Canadians need, be it their health care, education for their kids, roads, running various government departments, old age security and so forth.
We also know we want to design a tax system with few inefficiencies, with as much neutrality as possible, with this concept called integration and in which we avoid such practices as surplus stripping for tax avoidance strategies that some corporations and individuals can currently take advantage of to lower their tax bills, which I don't think is efficient or fair. We want a tax system that does not result in, as you point out, extreme wealth inequality. That's something we need to look at.
We have a progressive tax system, but we also have a tax system right now where there's a differential in the tax rates between dividends, interest and capital gains. We have moved to put more integration in the tax system.
I'm going back to your comments on health care because I truly believe our doctors and professionals should not really be depending on our tax system to create wealth for themselves. They should be depending on their salaries. They should be compensated fairly for that.
There was the debate on passive and active income, and there is now the debate on capital gains. At the provincial level, we need to understand that our doctors need to be paid more. I think in the province of British Columbia they are going down that route. The compensation system needs to change because we shouldn't even be having that argument or conversation about how we pay our doctors. We need to pay them well. They're very important, but they should not have to depend on generating capital gains within their corporation for their livelihood.
Would you not agree with that, sir?
:
In general, yes. If you have a problem with how much people are paid in a public utility, essentially, like health care, then first of all, verify if it's the case. If it's the case, pay them more and see if it has the desired impact.
On the more general principle, governments have to decide how much revenue they need. That's obviously a fungible proposition, and people can debate it—that's fair enough—but then who do you get it from?
To me, this debate is actually a little bit simpler than all of the arcane arguments about incentives and so on. If we need more revenues, either to balance the books or to fund programs people want and the government in power wants to pursue, you have to decide who you get it from. This gets a little bit more from the people who have more. From a health perspective, equity is better. Equity means better health status and probably, in the long run, reduces demand on the health care system.
I doubt you will find many population health researchers—or anybody who is concerned about health status and the productivity that's associated with people who have poor health status and all of those other things—who don't point to examples around the world where less equal societies, both in terms of income and wealth concentration, aren't healthier. They are healthier.
I'm a health policy person. I've been in the health field all of my life. As you say, I'm also an entrepreneur who uses the tax system in all of the ridiculous ways the tax system creates incentives for me to use it. I have gotten richer because of the capital gains tax as it was before, the treatment of dividends and the ability to smooth out my income, etc.
:
I know my time is short.
As an economist and someone who did his degree at Simon Fraser, before going to U of T, I concur with your thoughts. Our goal is to raise the standard of living for all Canadians, create wealth and create jobs, but also not create wealth inequality while we're doing that. That's the last thing we should be doing.
The capital gains effective tax rate is at 25% right now. Literally, people selling stock or a piece of land that they've owned for a long time do very well, especially when the government has put in infrastructure around that land. Think about this. The taxpayers fund all the infrastructure around a piece of land. The person who has owned the land for many years now benefits, because the value of the land has increased exponentially, while the cost of making that value increase was borne by the taxpayers of Canada or by a region.
We have many instances of that in the GTA. The person then sells the land and benefits handsomely. There's nothing wrong with that individual paying and providing a little bit more, so we can provide such programs as the Canadian dental care plan, the Canada child benefit and an early learning and national day care plan.
I look forward to having that debate in the weeks and months ahead.
Thank you.
:
Generally speaking, the more something is subject to taxation, the less of it we have. This is the case when it comes to increasing the capital gains inclusion rate. We haven't done a specific analysis of the impact it would have on investment and productivity. However, as I mentioned, when something is subject to taxation, people tend to provide a little less of it, so presumably this measure would have a negative impact on investment.
However, there are measures that have the opposite effect. One example is the Canadian entrepreneur incentive, through which the portion of capital gains that will be exempt will increase by $200,000 a year until 2035, I believe.
The proposed measure therefore contains a number of things. It could be felt that some elements will reduce investment incentives, but that others will encourage investments in certain categories, particularly as regards the incentive for Canadian entrepreneurs. That said, there are eligibility criteria. For eligible sectors, it will increase investment incentives in certain sectors and in a certain income bracket.
Ms. Miller, ever since the 1960s, when the Macdonald commission, which studied our taxation system, came up with the famous axiom that a buck is a buck is a buck. We have been seized with the idea that a dollar of income should be taxed the same, as a fundamental matter of principle.
If you're lucky enough to be wealthy and you can get income in the form of a dividend, then you get a dividend tax credit. If you're fortunate enough to have some of your income come in the form of a capital gain, you get half of your capital gain, up to $250,000, tax free. This measure is saying, simply, that one-third of the income above $250,000 will still be tax free.
What do you have to say about that principle of treating tax dollars the same, especially when people like waiters and waitresses, nurses, teachers, plumbers, truck drivers and warehouse people have to pay taxes on 100% of their incomes and don't have these privileges.
What's your sense about the impact of that on our tax system?
Mr. Moody, earlier we had several witnesses who disputed or downplayed the notion that there's a difference in risk or that, just because a person is self-employed or an entrepreneur, they don't really endure risk. It's occurred to me that you forgo all kinds of other protections in law that employees have. You have unlimited liability for anything that your employees might do. Your family's assets are all at risk. You lack access to benefits. You don't get paid for vacation. You don't even get a minimum wage. You might actually work and get paid less than that would allow. In your opening statement—the first time you tried it, anyway—you talked about the differences in risk.
Can you talk about how self-employed people, who have a corporate structure and have to save for their own retirements, do, in fact, endure risk, and how the system is supposed to mitigate some of that risk and allow people an opportunity to save for themselves and for their retirements?
:
Thank you, Mr. Kelly. Yes, I was trying to go down that avenue.
A simple, blunt response to the statement that entrepreneurial risk and employment risk, for example, are equal is that's just nonsense. I always challenge people who say that to put their money where their mouth is. If they think it's equal, then go and start a business, go and buy a building, because it's pretty damned risky.
I experienced it myself. All of my clients who are entrepreneurs—we have many of them—experience the ups and downs, and there are a lot of downs. The short answer is that the tax system, in my view, has done a nice job historically of acknowledging that risk and encouraging entrepreneurs to take that risk.
:
No. I think that's exactly right. These broad-based measures create a lot of unintended consequences and, frankly, unintended beneficiaries—or perhaps intended—when you use them.
As we said at the beginning, a tax regime can't do everything about everything. It can do a lot about equity and fairness. Any measure that is relatively modest and increases to some modest extent equity and fairness actually does more for the economy than the alleged prices.
I'll say one final thing. To those who say, “Well, it's going to make people leave the country,” or “It's going to affect investment decisions in a major way,” yes, moving out of the country is always an alternative. If you want to go and hunt down a lower tax rate, you always have that option if your capital is mobile. On the other hand, for people like me, what do you think I'm going to do about this increase as an alternative to generate a better return, since I will still get a privileged return from the dividends and the lower tax rate?
For most people, there's simply no viable option, even if we don't like it. Even if I don't like paying more money, I'm still going to invest in exactly the same way because it's still a better deal tax-wise. It's probably, as Ms. Miller said, still an unfair deal, and only slightly less unfair in my favour.